Year | Laureate | Country | Schools of economic thought | Rationale | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1969 | ![]() | Ragnar Frisch | ![]() | "for having developed and applied dynamic models for the analysis of economic processes"[2] | |
![]() | Jan Tinbergen | ![]() | |||
1970 | ![]() | Paul Samuelson | ![]() | Keynesian | "for the scientific work through which he has developed static and dynamic economic theory and actively contributed to raising the level of analysis in economic science"[8] |
1971 | ![]() | Simon Kuznets | ![]() | Institutional | "for his empirically founded interpretation of economic growth which has led to new and deepened insight into the economic and social structure and process of development"[9] |
1972 | John Hicks | ![]() | Keynesian | "for their pioneering contributions to general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory."[10] | |
![]() | Kenneth Arrow | ![]() | Neoclassical | ||
1973 | Wassily Leontief | ![]() ![]() | "for the development of the input-output method and for its application to important economic problems"[11] | ||
1974 | ![]() | Gunnar Myrdal | ![]() | Monetarism | "for their pioneering work in the theory of money and economic fluctuations and for their penetrating analysis of the interdependence of economic, social and institutional phenomena."[12] |
![]() | Friedrich Hayek | ![]() ![]() | Austrian | ||
1975 | ![]() | Leonid Kantorovich | ![]() | "for their contributions to the theory of optimum allocation of resources"[13] | |
Tjalling Koopmans | ![]() ![]() | ||||
1976 | ![]() | Milton Friedman | ![]() | Chicago | "for his achievements in the fields of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilisation policy"[14] |
1977 | ![]() | Bertil Ohlin | ![]() | Stockholm | "for their pathbreaking contribution to the theory of international trade and internationalcapital movements"[15] |
![]() | James Meade | ![]() | Keynesian | ||
1978 | ![]() | Herbert A. Simon | ![]() | Carnegie | "for his pioneering research into the decision-making process within economic organizations"[16] |
1979 | Theodore Schultz | ![]() | Chicago | "for their pioneering research into economic development research with particular consideration of the problems of developing countries."[17] | |
Arthur Lewis | ![]() ![]() | ||||
1980 | Lawrence Klein | ![]() | Keynesian | "for the creation of econometric models and the application to the analysis of economic fluctuations and economic policies"[18] | |
1981 | James Tobin | ![]() | Keynesian | "for his analysis of financial markets and their relations to expenditure decisions, employment, production and prices"[19] | |
1982 | George Stigler | ![]() | Chicago | "for his seminal studies of industrial structures, functioning of markets and causes and effects of public regulation"[20] | |
1983 | ![]() | Gérard Debreu | ![]() | Neoclassical | "for having incorporated new analytical methods into economic theory and for his rigorous reformulation of the theory of general equilibrium"[21] |
1984 | Richard Stone | ![]() | "for having made fundamental contributions to the development of systems of national accounts and hence greatly improved the basis for empirical economic analysis"[22] | ||
1985 | ![]() | Franco Modigliani | ![]() | Keynesian | "for his pioneering analyses of saving and of financial markets"[23] |
1986 | ![]() | James M. Buchanan | ![]() | Chicago | "for his development of the contractual and constitutional bases for the theory of economic and political decision-making"[24] |
1987 | ![]() | Robert Solow | ![]() | Keynesian | "for his contributions to the theory of economic growth"[25] |
1988 | ![]() | Maurice Allais | ![]() | Neoclassical | "for his pioneering contributions to the theory of markets and efficient utilization of resources"[26] |
1989 | ![]() | Trygve Haavelmo | ![]() | Keynesian | "for his clarification of the probability theory foundations of econometrics and his analyses of simultaneous economic structures"[27] |
1990 | Harry Markowitz | ![]() | Chicago | "for their pioneering work in the theory of financial economics"[28] | |
Merton Miller | Chicago | ||||
![]() | William Forsyth Sharpe | ||||
1991 | Ronald Coase | ![]() | Chicago | "for his discovery and clarification of the significance of transaction costs and property rights for the institutional structure and functioning of the economy"[29] | |
1992 | ![]() | Gary Becker | ![]() | Chicago | "for having extended the domain of microeconomic analysis to a wide range of human behaviour and interaction, including non-market behaviour"[30] |
1993 | ![]() | Robert Fogel | ![]() | Chicago | "for having renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods in order to explain economic and institutional change"[31] |
Douglass North | New institutional | ||||
1994 | John Harsanyi | ![]() | "for their pioneering analysis of equilibria in the theory of non-cooperative games."[32] | ||
![]() | John Forbes Nash | ||||
![]() | Reinhard Selten | ![]() | |||
1995 | Robert Lucas, Jr. | ![]() | New classical | "for having developed and applied the hypothesis of rational expectations, and thereby having transformed macroeconomic analysis and deepened our understanding of economic policy"[33] | |
1996 | James Mirrlees | ![]() | "for their fundamental contributions to the economic theory of incentives under asymmetric information"[34] | ||
William Vickrey | ![]() ![]() | Keynesian | |||
1997 | ![]() | Robert C. Merton | ![]() | "for a new method to determine the value of derivatives."[35] | |
![]() | Myron Scholes | ![]() ![]() | Chicago | ||
1998 | ![]() | Amartya Sen | ![]() | Capability approach | "for his contributions to welfare economics"[36] |
1999 | ![]() | Robert Mundell | ![]() | Keynesian | "for his analysis of monetary and fiscal policy under different exchange rate regimes and his analysis of optimum currency areas"[37] |
2000 | ![]() | James Heckman | ![]() | Chicago | "for his development of theory and methods for analyzing selective samples"[38] |
![]() | Daniel McFadden | ![]() | "for his development of theory and methods for analyzing discrete choice"[38] | ||
2001 | ![]() | George Akerlof | ![]() | Keynesian | "for their analyses of markets with asymmetric information"[39] |
![]() | Michael Spence | ||||
![]() | Joseph E. Stiglitz | Keynesian | |||
2002 | ![]() | Daniel Kahneman | ![]() ![]() | Behavioral | "for having integrated insights from psychological research into economic science, especially concerning human judgment and decision-making under uncertainty"[40] |
![]() | Vernon L. Smith | ![]() | New classical | "for having established laboratory experiments as a tool in empirical economic analysis, especially in the study of alternative market mechanisms"[40] | |
2003 | ![]() | Robert F. Engle | ![]() | "for methods of analyzing economic time series with time-varying volatility (ARCH)"[41] | |
![]() | Clive Granger | ![]() | "for methods of analyzing economic time series with common trends (cointegration)"[41] | ||
2004 | ![]() | Finn E. Kydland | ![]() | New classical | "for their contributions to dynamic macroeconomics: the time consistency of economic policy and the driving forces behind business cycles."[42] |
![]() | Edward C. Prescott | ![]() | New classical | ||
2005 | ![]() | Robert J. Aumann | ![]() ![]() | "for having enhanced our understanding of conflict and cooperation through game-theoryanalysis."[43] | |
![]() | Thomas C. Schelling | ![]() | |||
2006 | ![]() | Edmund S. Phelps | ![]() | "for his analysis of intertemporal tradeoffs in macroeconomic policy"[44] | |
2007 | ![]() | Leonid Hurwicz | ![]() ![]() | "for having laid the foundations of mechanism design theory"[45] | |
![]() | Eric S. Maskin | ![]() | |||
![]() | Roger B. Myerson | ||||
2008 | ![]() | Paul Krugman | ![]() | Keynesian | "for his analysis of trade patterns and location of economic activity"[46] |
2009 | ![]() | Elinor Ostrom | ![]() | New institutional | "for her analysis of economic governance, especially the commons"[47] |
![]() | Oliver E. Williamson | New institutional | "for his analysis of economic governance, especially the boundaries of the firm"[47] | ||
2010 | ![]() | Peter A. Diamond | ![]() | "for their analysis of markets with search frictions"[48] | |
![]() | Dale T. Mortensen | ||||
![]() | Christopher A. Pissarides | ![]() | |||
2011 | ![]() | Thomas J. Sargent | ![]() | Neoclassical | "for their empirical research on cause and effect in the macroeconomy" |
![]() | Christopher A. Sims | Neoclassical | |||
2012 | ![]() | Alvin E. Roth | ![]() | "for the theory of stable allocations and the practice of market design." | |
![]() | Lloyd S. Shapley | ||||
2013 | ![]() | Eugene F. Fama | ![]() | Chicago | "for their empirical analysis of asset prices." |
![]() | Lars Peter Hansen | Chicago | |||
![]() | Robert J. Shiller | Keynesian | |||
2014 | Jean Tirole | ![]() | "for his analysis of market power and regulation". |
Friday, February 27, 2015
List of Nobel Memorial Prize laureates in Economics
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)